ROUND TABLE

 

Can performance-based financing be used to reform health systems in developing countries?

 

Le financement lié aux résultats peut-il être utilisé pour réformer les systèmes de santé dans les pays en voie de développement ?

 

¿Se puede utilizar la financiación basada en el rendimiento para reformar los sistemas sanitarios en países en desarrollo?

 

 

Megan IrelandI,*; Elisabeth PaulII; Bruno DujardinI

ISchool of Public Health, Université Libre de Bruxelles, 50 avenue FD Roosevelt, Brussels, Belgium
II
Department of Social Change and Development, Université de Liège, Belgium

 

 


ABSTRACT

Over the past 15 years, performance-based financing has been implemented in an increasing number of developing countries, particularly in Africa, as a means of improving health worker performance. Scaling up to national implementation in Burundi and Rwanda has encouraged proponents of performance-based financing to view it as more than a financing mechanism, but increasingly as a strategic tool to reform the health sector. We resist such a notion on the grounds that results-based and economically driven interventions do not, on their own, adequately respond to patient and community needs, upon which health system reform should be based. We also think the debate surrounding performance-based financing is biased by insufficient and unsubstantiated evidence that does not adequately take account of context nor disentangle the various elements of the performance-based financing package.




RÉSUMÉ

Au cours des 15 dernières années, le financement basé sur les nous opposons à cette opinion, arguant que les interventions basées sur résultats a été mis en place dans un nombre croissant de pays en les résultats et dictées par des considérations économiques ne répondent voie de développement, en particulier en Afrique, comme un moyen pas de manière adéquate, à elles seules, aux besoins des patients et de la d'améliorer les résultats du personnel soignant. Le passage à la mise communauté, sur lesquels la réforme du système de santé doit reposer. en place nationale, au Burundi et au Rwanda, du financement basé sur Nous pensons également que le débat autour du financement basé sur les résultats a encouragé ses partisans à le considérer comme étant plus les résultats est influencé par des preuves insuffisantes et non fondées qu'un simple mécanisme de financement, mais de plus en plus comme qui ne prennent pas correctement en compte le contexte ni ne démêlent un outil stratégique permettant de réformer le secteur de la santé. Nous les différents éléments du plan de financement basé sur les résultats.



RESUMEN

Durante los últimos 15 años, la financiación basada en el rendimiento se en Burundi y Ruanda ha animado a los partidarios de la financiación ha implementado en un número cada vez mayor de países en desarrollo, basada en el rendimiento a que se considere como algo más que un particularmente en África, como un medio para mejorar el rendimiento mero mecanismo de financiación y a que se tenga en cuenta cada del trabajador sanitario. La ampliación de la implementación nacional vez más como una herramienta estratégica utilizada para reformar el sector sanitario. Nos oponemos a dicha noción, basándonos en que las intervenciones basadas en los resultados y motivadas por la economía no responden adecuadamente, por sí mismas, a las necesidades de los pacientes y la comunidad, que es en lo que se debería basar la reforma del sistema sanitario. También opinamos que el debate sobre la financiación basada en el rendimiento está sesgado por la falta de evidencias y por fundamentos que no tienen en cuenta el contexto adecuadamente y que no esclarecen los diversos elementos incluidos en el paquete de financiación basada en el rendimiento.


 

 

Introduction

Performance-based financing (PBF) is an intervention that is gaining significant momentum as a solution to poor performance and the health worker crisis in low-income countries, particularly in Africa.1 Results indicate that PBF can play a role in increasing the productivity of health workers and have positive effects on health service utilization.2–5 The increasing use of PBF and its perceived benefits is now leading proponents to promote it as a strategy to address structural problems and to introduce more generalized health system reform, as testified by the recent paper in the Bulletin of the World Health Organization "Performance-based financing: just a donor fad or a catalyst towards comprehensive health-care reform?".1 We believe that the current optimism for such a strategy is unsubstantiated and underestimates important constraints to its implementation. It also risks falling into the trap of seeking a "magic bullet" solution to improve complex social systems.

 

Lack of evidence

PBF is an intervention designed to increase the quantity and quality of health care based on the theory that providing financial incentives to health workers for meeting output targets will motivate them to produce more or better outcomes and hence improve their performance. While the proponents of PBF make grand claims about its achievements and potential, an overview of the literature reveals that there is very little evidence to support these claims.6–10 This is largely due to the fact that it is very difficult to evaluate PBF. To date most studies have sweepingly attributed most or all changes at district health facility level to the PBF intervention with little or no regard for contributing factors nor insight into how or why changes have occurred.6–10 To our knowledge, only one evaluation in Rwanda3 was carried out that isolates the effect of PBF incentives from increased resources. PBF is a comprehensive intervention in a complex, context-specific system. It seeks to improve the health sector by changing the organizational structure of the health system with regard to its financing mechanisms, information systems, planning, monitoring and evaluation. Any evaluation therefore needs to account for such methodological challenges and take into account the context (economic, social, political), as well as the content and the process of implementation. While the Rwandan study can give us more insight into that country's particular case, quasi-experimental evaluation designs are limited in evaluating interventions that have such high variance (context, content, process).11 Arguably, the focus should be on the reasons why and how the intervention is working rather than whether or not it is working.

 

What are the side-effects?

An overview of the literature on PBF not only highlights weak evaluations with questionable study designs but also several other anomalies. Possible adverse effects that financial incentives can have on health worker motivation and performance include: focusing on targeted services at the expense of other services (distortions); false reporting (gaming); cherry-picking patients that make it easier to meet targets; focusing on quantity rather than quality of services because it is methodologically easier to implement and monitor; increasing inequity by rewarding providers and facilities that are in a better position to meet targets; temporary improvements to services that cease as soon as the target is lifted; and dilution of intrinsic motivation.12 Despite significant documentation regarding these effects, there have not been any studies to evaluate their impact.6,10 This absence of evaluation of the possible negative consequences of PBF is reflected in a favourable bias for PBF in the literature. This is due both to a publishing bias towards studies that demonstrate successful implementation and the fact that most published authors are actively involved in the implementation of PBF initiatives.

 

Is it efficient?

After more than a decade of implementation it is time to give serious consideration to efficiency, i.e. maximizing the level and quality of health system output while minimizing costs. There is very little, if any, evidence of the cost-effectiveness of PBF.8,13 In addition to the extra funding needed to pay incentives and thus increase health-worker earnings, the transaction costs of PBF implementation are necessarily high. In most cases there is a need for new bodies or structures (from independent purchasing bodies to civil society organizations charged with community oversight) and strengthening of existing structures (especially health information systems). It would appear that the opportunity costs are also high. Health workers have increased reporting and administrative burdens14 due to the effort required for monitoring and evaluating performance targets. This is not only to enable the accurate allocation of premiums but also to ensure against "gaming" and should, although this is rarely the case, also monitor for potential adverse effects on non-targeted activities. As PBF gains increasing support and a growing number of countries implement, or plan to introduce it, it is paramount to start taking account of the real costs and benefits and financial sustainability of PBF interventions.

 

Is it replicable?

We notice in the literature that most claims of the success of PBF pertain to Rwanda. Rwanda was one of the first developing countries to implement PBF and was the first country to implement it on a national scale and is therefore an important case to study. However, the fact that PBF implementation has been successful in Rwanda is not grounds on which to believe that this intervention can be successfully replicated elsewhere – a concern shared by others, as recently published in the Lancet.15 The success (or failure) of PBF, as a comprehensive social intervention, is entirely dependent on the context. Many authors have defined conditions necessary for the success of PBF such as: strong leadership and management support, accurate information and reporting systems, increased funding and training.7,8,12,16 It would appear that Rwanda had the right conditions to effectively take on the challenge of implementing a successful PBF intervention. However, it should not be presumed that this is easily achieved elsewhere. Because PBF is a comprehensive package of reforms, a range of technical as well as contextual constraints can significantly hinder its implementation. Examples of constraints include: the need to have the management capacity at national and local level for effective implementation; the need for a flexible public finance management system that has the capacity to easily mobilize resources to the local level; and the significant methodological challenge of designing a reward system that is equitable, socially acceptable and that promotes quality as highly as quantity of both targeted and non-targeted services.

In addition to technical conditions, the contextual country conditions are equally important for success. As a package of interventions, greater analysis is needed into which elements of the package are most beneficial and the reasons for this. For example, the payment of incentives (the only defining feature of the package specific to PBF) in relation to other elements such as increased coaching, supervision, accountability, increased salaries and increased spending for health.

We argue therefore that a more comprehensive evaluation, supported by clear evidence, should be used to inform the debate about PBF. One of the main reasons for the Rwandan success is strong leadership and political will. However, this political motivation has effectively stifled debate on the topic, making it difficult for stakeholders to raise concerns, for example, about unintended adverse consequences. This sensitivity contributes to the favourable bias but is unhelpful in informing the discussion on the development of PBF. During recent field visits to Rwanda, we have observed waning enthusiasm from health workers who have become accustomed to receiving financial incentives and we therefore question their sustainability as a motivating factor.

 

Basis for reform

The relative success and interest in PBF suggest that it has a role to play in improving health-worker performance but we resist the notion that it can be applied as a foundation to health system reform in low-income countries. By nature, PBF is economically driven and focuses principally on public finance. Indeed it is assumed that PBF is equally applicable to other sectors1 but as such it overlooks the human dimension to development. The world health report 2008: primary healthcare now more than ever17 reminds us that better health outcomes are best achieved when service delivery is organized around people's needs and expectations and that "putting people first" should be the focus of reforms. But the setting of service delivery targets actually risks creating a conflict of interest between patients and providers and can act as a disincentive to patient-centred care. For example, the successful referral of a pregnant woman to a health centre or hospital for delivery is, above all, dependant on the quality of the relationship between the woman and her health provider. It is counter-intuitive to expect that fulfilling antenatal targets will automatically create a good relationship that will ensure follow-up care and a positive outcome of her pregnancy.

PBF has international support because it fits neatly into the Millennium Development Goals aid paradigm for rapid progress on a few key indicators. But we think it is misplaced to focus on outcomes and results without a thorough understanding and development of the processes and relationships that are necessary to obtain sustained improvements and quality of care. While quantitative targets can encourage creativity to increasing access, we wonder if quality of health care can ever really be improved when the system and its providers focus on targets linked to financial gain instead of on patient-centred care and the needs of the populations they serve. History has shown us that there are no "magic bullet" solutions for reforming the health sector and, while good financial management is necessary, it cannot be the motor of reform.

Competing interests: None declared.

 

References

1. Meessen B, Soucat A, Sekabaraga C. Performance-based financing: just a donor fad or a catalyst towards comprehensive health-care reform? Bull World Health Organ 2011;89:153–6. doi:10.2471/BLT.10.077339 PMID:21346927        

2. Eichler R. Can "pay for performance" increase utilization by the poor and improve the quality of health services. [Discussion paper for the first meeting of the Working Group on Performance Based Incentives]. Washington: Centre for Global Development; 2006. Available from: http://www.eldis.org/vfile/upload/1/document/0708/DOC23033.pdf [accessed 29 June 2011].         

3. Basinga P, Gertler PJ, Binagwaho A, Soucat ALB, Sturdy J, Vermeersch CMJ. Effect on maternal and child health services in Rwanda of payment to primary health-care providers for performance: an impact evaluation. Lancet 2011;377:1421–8. doi:10.1016/S0140-6736(11)60177-3 PMID:21515164        

4. Soeters R, Habineza C, Peerenboom PB. Performance-based financing and changing the district health system: experience from Rwanda. Bull World Health Organ 2006;84:884–9. PMID:17143462        

5. Meessen B, Kashala JPI, Musango L. Output-based payment to boost staff productivity in public health centres: contracting in Kabutare district, Rwanda. Bull World Health Organ 2007;85:108–15. doi:10.2471/BLT.06.032110 PMID:17308731        

6. Oxman AD, Fretheim A. Can paying for results help to achieve the Millennium Development Goals? A critical review of selected evaluations of results-based financing. Journal of Evidence Based Medicine. 2009;2:184–95. doi:10.1111/j.1756-5391.2009.01024.x PMID:21349012        

7. Eldridge C, Palmer N. Performance-based payment: some reflections on the discourse, evidence and unanswered questions. Health Policy Plan 2009;24:160. doi:10.1093/heapol/czp002 PMID:19202163        

8. Brenzel L, Measham A, Naimoli J, Batson A, Bredenkamp C, Skolnik R. Taking stock: World Bank experience with results-based financing (RBF) for health. Washington: The World Bank; 2009.         

9. Scheffler R. Pay for performance, programs in health services: what is the evidence? [World Health Report 2010 background paper 31]. Geneva: World Health Organization; 2010.         

10. Toonen J, Canavan A, Vergeer P, Elovainio R. Learning lessons on implementing performance based financing from a multi-country evaluation. Amsterdam: KIT (Royal Tropical Institute); 2009.         

11. Walshe K. Understanding what works – and why – in quality improvement: the need for theory-driven evaluation. Int J Qual Health Care 2007;19:57. doi:10.1093/intqhc/mzm004 PMID:17337518        

12. Oxman AD, Fretheim A. An overview of research on the effects of results-based financing [Report no. 16-2008]. Oslo: Norwegian Knowledge Centre for the Health Services; 2008.         

13. Oxman AD, Fretheim A. Can paying for results help to achieve the Millennium Development Goals? Overview of the effectiveness of results based financing. Journal of Evidence Based Medicine. 2009;2:70–83. doi:10.1111/j.1756-5391.2009.01020.x PMID:21348993        

14. Kalk A, Paul FA, Grabosch E. "Paying for performance" in Rwanda: does it pay off? Trop Med Int Health 2010;15:182–90. doi:10.1111/j.1365-3156.2009.02430.x PMID:19930141        

15. Montagu D, Yamey G. Pay-for-performance and the Millennium Development Goals. Lancet 2011;377:1383–5. doi:10.1016/S0140-6736(11)60544-8 PMID:21515147        

16. Canavan A, Toonen J, Elovainio R. Performance based financing: an international review of the literature. Amsterdam: KIT (Royal Tropical Institute); 2008.         

17. The world health report 2008: primary health care now more than ever. Geneva: World Health Organization; 2008.         

 

 

(Submitted: 16 February 2011 – Revised version received: 27 April 2011 – Accepted: 28 April 2011)

 

 

* Correspondence to Megan Ireland (e-mail: megan.ireland@ulb.ac.be)

World Health Organization Genebra - Genebra - Switzerland
E-mail: bulletin@who.int